There
is a tendency among some environmental writers to dismiss “classical”,
“traditional”, “neoliberal”, or “mainstream” economics as somehow inimical to
environmental interests.
The
problem is that more often than not these writers get the facts wrong.
It’s
almost as if the knee-jerk aversion to economics that exists among many
environmentalists prevents them from acknowledging the truth: that mainstream
economics is very much on their side. While criticizing economics may help them
polish their leftist credentials and demonstrate the contrarian-independent
thinking that grabs headlines, it ultimately leads to sloppy thinking.
Case
in point are recent pieces by David Roberts of Grist and Bill McKibben in
The New Republic (for the record: I respect both authors and they do good
work).
McKibben
describes how the Waxman-Markey climate change bill is full of loopholes for
special interests (which it is), and uses this as evidence against the basic
economic rationale for a cap and trade bill. He then praises the new CLEAR bill
sponsored by Senators Maria Cantwell and Susan Collins for its fairness, lack
of loopholes, and simplicity. He suggests that it represents a significant
departure from traditional economics—the subtitle of his piece is “Forget Cap
and Trade”—when in fact the bill is nothing but a cap and trade bill with full auctions
and consumer rebates.
The
CLEAR bill represents a policy that mainstream environmental economists—from
Robert Stavins (Harvard) to Michael Hanemann (UC-Berkeley)—have advocated in
one form or another for well over a decade; it is what I have taught and
advocated in graduate school every semester for the past seven years.
CLEAR
is superior to the Waxman-Markey bill not
because it deviates from the prescriptions of classical environmental economics,
but because it adheres to them so
closely.
Now
for the relatively recent David Roberts piece, “Economics
as Pathology”, in Grist (one of dozens of pieces over the years where
Roberts lambasts mainstream economics). Roberts slams “neoliberal” economics
for its insistence on rationality as the guiding principle for human activity;
since people don’t act rationally all of the time, Roberts believes this
insistence has hampered the search for solutions to climate change.
Roberts,
for all of his excellent contributions to the climate change debate, insists on
a myopic and caricaturized version of economics that simply doesn’t exist. Even
the leaders of the behavioral economics revolution that he admires so much are
all mainstream economists in the world’s leading institutions—e.g. Sendil
Mullinathan of MIT, Richard Thaler at the University of Chicago, and Matthew
Rabin at UC-Berkeley.
In
fact, the leading proponents of decisive action on climate change are as
mainstream as they come: William
Norhaus (Yale), Paul
Krugman (Princeton), Martin
Weitzman (Harvard), and even Gregory
Mankiw (Harvard, former Chair of the Council of Economic Advisors under
President Bush). All are extremely prestigious, and all adhere to a largely
classical (i.e. neoliberal) economic view. Put them together in a room, and I’m
sure they would ultimately agree that we need a range of policies to complement
carbon pricing; they recognize that changing both consumer and producer
behavior on such a massive scale will require more than just price signals.
They might not agree completely on all of the prescriptions but neither do
environmentalists.
Economists
of all stripes have argued for decades for the proper pricing of pollution, for
severely reducing or eliminating natural resources subsidies for agriculture,
forestry, energy, water, and fisheries, and for making property rights simpler
and more transparent.
So
here’s the bottom line: when they discuss policy solutions to environmental
problems, Roberts and McKibben (and virtually every other environmentalist) are
three out of four times describing concepts that can be traced to mainstream
environmental economists, sometimes from work done decades ago.
Of
course economists don’t agree on everything, and there is always some economist
hack at one of the rightwing “think tanks” who will put forth an outlandish
idea—but by and large the most well-respected mainstream economists are
squarely on the side of environmentalists.
It
would be nice if more environmentalists would simply acknowledge this, and we
could all work together to help the public understand the strong synergy
between economic and environmental interests. The idea that classical economics
is somehow opposed to environmental legislation, or not sophisticated enough to
grasp the realities of human behavior, is false. Worse, it creates a false
dichotomy that only helps fuel the skeptics and confuse an already chronically
misinformed citizenry.
P.S. In a subsequent
piece I will explain why these issues are so critical for framing the
legislative battles in the months and years ahead.